Asset Allocation. William Kinlaw

Читать онлайн.
Название Asset Allocation
Автор произведения William Kinlaw
Жанр Ценные бумаги, инвестиции
Серия
Издательство Ценные бумаги, инвестиции
Год выпуска 0
isbn 9781119817727



Скачать книгу

and Capital Flows,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 60, No. 4.

      2 Kinlaw, W., Kritzman, M., and Mao, J. 2015. “The Components of Private Equity Performance,” Journal of Alternative Investments, Vol. 18, No. 2 (Fall).

      1 1. See Kaplan and Schoar (2005).

      2 2. See Kinlaw, Kritzman, and Mao (2015).

      THE FOUNDATION: PORTFOLIO THEORY

      E-V Maxim

      Expected Return

      Markowitz showed that a portfolio's expected return is simply the weighted average of the expected returns of its component asset classes. A portfolio's variance is a more complicated concept, however. It depends on more than just the variances of the component asset classes.

      Risk

      The variance of an individual asset class is a measure of the dispersion of its returns. It is calculated by squaring the difference between each return in a series and the mean return for the series, and then averaging these squared differences. The square root of the variance (the standard deviation) is usually used in practice because it measures dispersion in the same units in which the underlying return is measured.

      To quantify co-movement among security returns, Markowitz applied the statistical concept of covariance. The covariance between two asset classes equals the standard deviation of the first times the standard deviation of the second times the correlation between the two.

      The correlation, in this context, measures the association between the returns of two asset classes. It ranges in value from 1 to –1. If the returns of one asset class are higher than its average return when the returns of another asset class are higher than its average return, for example, the correlation coefficient will be positive, somewhere between 0 and 1. Alternatively, if the returns of one asset class are lower than its average return when the returns of another asset class are higher than its average return, then the correlation will be negative.

      The correlation, by itself, is an inadequate measure of covariance because it measures only the direction and degree of association between the returns of the asset classes. It does not account for the magnitude of variability in the returns of each asset class. Covariance captures magnitude by multiplying the correlation by the standard deviations of the returns of the asset classes.

      Consider, for example, the covariance of an asset class with itself. Obviously, the correlation in this case equals 1. The covariance of an asset class with itself thus equals the standard deviation of its returns squared, which is its variance.

      Finally, portfolio variance also depends on the weightings of its constituent asset classes – the proportion of a portfolio's wealth invested in each asset class. The variance of a portfolio consisting of two asset classes equals the variance of the first asset class times its weighting squared plus the variance of the second asset class times its weighting squared plus twice the covariance between the asset classes times the weighting of each asset class. The standard deviation of this portfolio equals the square root of the variance.

      From this formulation of portfolio risk, Markowitz was able to offer two key insights. First, unless the asset classes in a portfolio are perfectly inversely correlated (that is, have a correlation of –1), it is not possible to eliminate portfolio risk entirely through diversification. If a portfolio is divided equally among its component asset classes, for example, as the number of asset classes in the portfolio increases, the portfolio's variance will tend not toward zero but, rather, toward the average covariance of the component asset classes.

      Efficient Frontier

      Markowitz also demonstrated that, for given levels of risk, we can identify particular combinations of asset classes that maximize expected return. He deemed these portfolios “efficient” and referred to a continuum of such portfolios in dimensions of expected return and standard deviation as the efficient frontier. According to Markowitz's E-V maxim, investors should choose portfolios located along the efficient frontier. It is almost always the case that there exists some portfolio on the efficient frontier that offers a higher expected return and less risk than the least risky of its component asset classes (assuming the least risky asset class is not completely risk free). However, the portfolio with the highest expected return will always be allocated entirely to the asset class with the highest expected return (assuming no leverage).

      The Optimal Portfolio

      Though all the portfolios along the efficient frontier are efficient, only one portfolio is most suitable for a particular investor. This portfolio is called the optimal portfolio. The theoretical approach for identifying the optimal portfolio is to specify how many units of expected return an investor is willing to give up to reduce the portfolio's risk by one unit. If, for example, the investor is willing to give up two units of expected return to lower portfolio variance (the squared value of the standard deviation) by one unit, his risk aversion would equal 2. The investor would then draw a line with a slope of 2 and find the point of tangency of this line with the efficient frontier (with risk defined as variance rather than standard deviation). The portfolio located at this point of tangency is theoretically optimal because its risk/return trade-off matches the investor's preference for balancing risk and return.

      Before