Military Alliances in the Twenty-First Century. Alexander Lanoszka

Читать онлайн.
Название Military Alliances in the Twenty-First Century
Автор произведения Alexander Lanoszka
Жанр Социальная психология
Серия
Издательство Социальная психология
Год выпуска 0
isbn 9781509545582



Скачать книгу

that the costs of aggression are too high for it to be worthwhile. Extended deterrence is a form of deterrence put into practice by a defender that wishes to prevent external aggression against another state – typically, a treaty ally. A defensive military alliance need not have to demonstrate that it would win a potential war for (extended) deterrence to work, but it must somehow convey that it has the political will, military capability, and resolve to inflict unacceptable pain on an adversary that it believes to be against the status quo (Jervis 1979). Deterrence is admittedly a deceptively simple concept. Just because an adversary has not acted aggressively does not necessarily mean that deterrence has worked. The adversary may never have had a desire to attack, making successful deterrence an illusion and thus a false positive (Lebow and Stein 1995). Divining adversarial intentions can be tricky, and with the stakes being sometimes existential, countries feel that they must err on the side of caution to undertake measures, like forming military alliances, to augment deterrence. And finally, deterrence does not imply having a militarily defensive strategy. Sometimes going on the offence is the best way to impose costs if deterrence fails.

      But what exactly is the danger that drives alliance formation? A classic explanation for why states establish defensive military alliances is that they are seeking to balance power. According to balance of power theory, states tend to band together so as to prevent a potential hegemon – that is, a state forecast to wield a preponderance of military and economic capabilities – from rising up and dominating the system (Levy 2004: 37). A military alliance can help reinforce the status quo and thus provide an invaluable tool for preserving it.

      Scholars have thus tried to refine balance of power theory to explain alliance formation better. Most notably, Stephen Walt (1987: 5) argues that states appraise others on the basis of perceived threat, which can be a composite of factors that include geography, perceived hostile intent, and offensive capabilities. In a twist on this argument, Paul Poast (2019) contends that compatibility in war plans and availability of outside options (buck-passing, unilateral action, or another alliance) drive alliance formation. Thomas Christensen and Jack Snyder postulate that if prevailing military technology favors the offence over the defense, then, all things being equal, states will be more likely to ally with one another against a common threat. The reasoning is simple. When defense is relatively easy, states might believe that others can do the fighting themselves against a perceived threat. Alliances do not happen – or at least will remain very weak – because of such “buck-passing” and “free riding.” However, if attacking is easier than defending, then the balance could be more easily overthrown. And so, “to uphold the balance and to have an effect on the outcome of the fighting, policymakers [believe] that they [have] to conclude binding alliances in advance and throw their full weight into the battle at the outset” (1990: 148). To be sure, according to Christensen and Snyder, such imperatives are most acute when more than two great powers among the states are present in a regional or international context – that is, under multipolarity. Otherwise, under bipolarity, whereby there are only two great powers of roughly equal standing, alliances should be much less consequential for actual war-fighting because no one ally or group thereof can tip the balance.