Innovation in Clusters. Estelle Vallier

Читать онлайн.
Название Innovation in Clusters
Автор произведения Estelle Vallier
Жанр Отраслевые издания
Серия
Издательство Отраслевые издания
Год выпуска 0
isbn 9781119881438



Скачать книгу

and their influence in France

      At the end of the 1970s, sociologists Arnaldo Bagnasco and Carlo Trigilia (1977, 1984, 1988) and economist Sebastiano Brusco (1982, 1986) published their research on the Third Italy, the term used to describe regions referred to as intermediate because of their geographical location between the highly industrial regions of northwestern Italy and the Mezzogiorno, characterized by a lower level of economic development. The Third Italy specializes “in traditional (clothing, footwear, leather, furniture, etc.) or more modern (small mechanics, electrical engineering, etc.) activities, whose production process can be easily broken down” (Daumas 2007, p. 133). The industrial organization of this area is characterized by a strong presence of small and medium-sized enterprises that participate only in certain phases of production and do not integrate a vertical model into their processes (as opposed to the mass production processes of large factories, especially in automobile production, further north). This would therefore be a dynamic specific to small businesses (Bagnasco 1977).

      A socioterritorial entity, characterized by the active association, in a circumscribed and historically determined territorial area, of a community of people and a population of industrial enterprises. In the district, unlike what happens in other environments, such as the manufacturing city, community and business tend to, as it were, interpenetrate (Daumas 2007, p. 134).

      Studies on the Third Italy thus revive and further develop Marshall’s concept of the district. They particularly emphasize the local accumulation of know-how, individual interdependencies and the interpenetration of businesses with a community of people.

      On the other hand, Raveyre and Saglio consider that cooperation is not only defensive but also oriented towards strategies of development and adaptation of the technical potential of local industries (ibid., p. 165). The system produces, through innovations, a disruption of the organization of work that translates into new trades and new training. Finally, another key element for the authors lies in the relations that the system maintains with local political authorities, which constitute a fundamental issue for the system’s sustainability (ibid., p. 174). In the local production systems studied by Courlet and Pecqueur (1992), the definition is broader than for the districts. They may therefore refer to similar activities in which enterprises cooperate on peripheral dimensions (transport, exports, etc.) or to complementary activities (Courlet 2002, p. 89) and, as a result, a network of subcontractors emerges (Guillaume 2008, p. 298). In some cases, businesses do not necessarily belong to the same sector and, unlike the district, do not participate in the multiple stages of industrial production. Moreover, the relationships are not familial, but professional and informal in a local productive system. In his work on the “Alpine furrow”, however, the geographer Bernard Pecqueur (1995) qualifies this aspect and identifies relatively poor direct relations between businesses. Each has its own regional, national and even European and global geography, and what link businesses together are the territorial resources they share. Housing, amenities, infrastructure, facilities and the skilled labor market thus tend to unify them.

      Despite some variations, both the Italian and French studies agree that the unit of analysis is not the enterprise, but the “district” as a whole, with interconnected firms (Brusco 1990). The focus has thus shifted from the enterprise itself to the space around it.

      1.1.3. The rise of districts: the end of the Fordist enterprise?

      However, this economic and social regulation, which was being carried out within large enterprises, is no longer appropriate. Indeed, the crisis of Fordism is reflected in a crisis of territory at the level of the nation state (caused by a triple movement of tertiarization, deregulation and globalization) and a crisis of legitimacy of the welfare state with the emergence of mass unemployment (Carré and Levratto 2011, p. 360). In this context of capital internationalization and the crisis of the state, institutional arrangements are regional (EU, NAFTA) and international (WTO, for example), rather than solely national. In France, some authors see a disappearance of the Colbertist state (Mustar and Laredo 2002) and the emergence of new public actors, such as Europe and local authorities. As a result, the new post-Fordist regulations would be posed jointly in terms of sector and territory (Laurent and Du Tertre 2008). This approach is in line with theories that consider that a new geography of flexible accumulation is emerging in reaction to the Fordist mode of accumulation (Storper and Scott 1990). In a seminal work, Michael Piore and Charles Sabel (1986) develop the concept of flexible specialization as an alternative model to Fordist mass production, based on the emergence of local industrial models, notably the Italian districts (Hirst and Zeitlin 1992). Industrialization with flexible specialization is understood to be: